1 A. Mesoudi, A. Whiten, K. N. Laland, Towards a unified science of cultural evolution. Behav. Brain Sci. 29, 329–347 (2006).2 D. Hirshleifer, Presidential address: Social transmission bias in economics and finance. J. Finance 75, 1779– 1831 (2020).3 R. J. Shiller, Narrative economics. Am. Econ. Rev. 107, 967– 1004 (2017).4 A. A. Alchian, Uncertainty, evolution and economic theory. J. Polit. Econ. 58, 211–221 (1950).5 F. Slanina, Essentials of Econophysics Modelling (Oxford University Press, 2014).6 J. D. Farmer, A. W. Lo, Frontiers of finance: Evolution and efficient markets. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. U.S.A. 96, 9991–9992 (1999).7 A. W. Lo, Adaptive Markets: Financial Evolution at the Speed of Thought (Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 2017).8 D. Hirshleifer, Behavioral finance. Annu. Rev. Financial Econ. 7, 133– 159 (2015).9 J. B. DeLong, A. Shleifer, L. Summers, R. J. Waldmann, Positive feedback investment strategies and destabilizing rational speculation. J. Finance 45, 375–395(1990).10 C. Lee, A. Shleifer, R. Thaler, Investor sentiment and the closed-end fund puzzle. J. Finance 46, 75– 109 (1991).11 M. Baker, J. Wurgler, Investor sentiment in the stock market. J. Econ. Perspect. 21, 129– 151 (2007).12 I. V. Evstigneev, T. Hens, K. R. Schenk-Hoppe´,“ Evolutionary finance”in Handbook of Financial Markets: Dynamics and Evolution, T.Hens, K.R.S.Hoppe´, Eds. (Elsevier, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2009), pp. 507–566.13 L. Blume, D. Easley, Heterogeneity, selection, and wealth dynamics. Annu. Rev. Econ. 2, 425–450 (2010).14 R. Boyd, P. J. Richerson, Culture and the Evolutionary Process (University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL, 1985).15 B. LeBaron,“Agent-based computational finance”in Handbook of Computational Economics, L. Tesfatsion, K. L. Judd, Eds. (Elsevier, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2006), vol. 2, pp. 1187– 1233.16 C. H. Hommes, F. O. Wagener,“Complex evolutionary systems in behavioral finance”in Handbook of Financial Markets: Dynamics and Evolution, T. Hens,K. R. Schenk-Hopp, Eds. (Elsevier, Oxford, UK, 2009), pp. 217–276.17 T. Lux, S. Alfarano, Financial power laws: Empirical evidence, models, and mechanisms. Chaos Solit. Fractals 88, 3– 18 (2016).18 G. R. Price, Selection and covariance. Nature 227, 520–521 (1970).19 C. el Mouden, J. B. Andre´, O. Morin, D. Nettle, Cultural transmission and the evolution of human behaviour: A general approach based on the Price equation. J. Evol. Biol. 27, 231–241 (2014).20 E. G. Aguilar, E. Akçay, Gene-culture co-inheritance of a behavioral trait. Am. Nat. 192, 311–320 (2018).21 S. Shennan, Descent with modification and the archaeological record. Philos. Trans. Biol. Sci. 366, 1070– 1079 (2011).22 B. Han, D. A. Hirshleifer, J. Walden, Visibility bias in the transmission of consumption beliefs and undersaving. Rotman School of Management Working Paper No. 2798638 (2020). https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2798638. Accessed 8 February 2021.23 C. Heath, Do people prefer to pass along good or bad news? Valence and relevance as predictors of transmission propensity. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 68, 79–94 (1996).24 J. Berger, Arousal increases social transmission of information. Psychol. Sci. 22, 891–893 (2011).25 J. Henrich, The Secret of Our Success: How Culture Is Driving Human Evolution, Domesticating Our Species, and Making Us Smarter (Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 2015).26 M. J. Brennan, F. Li, W. N. Torous, Dollar cost averaging. Rev. Finance 9, 509–535 (2005).27 V. Rantala, How do investment ideas spread through social interaction? Evidence from a Ponzi scheme. J. Finance 74, 2349–2389 (2019).28 J. D. Farmer, Market force, ecology, and evolution. Ind. Corp. Change 11, 895–953 (2002).29 D. Hirshleifer, Psychological bias as a driver of financial regulation. Eur. Financ. Manag. 14, 856–874 (2008).30 R. Mace, C. J. Holden, A phylogenetic approach to cultural evolution. Trends Ecol. Evol. 20, 116– 121 (2005).31 L. Guiso, P. Sapienza, L. Zingales, Does culture affect economic outcomes? J. Econ. Perspect. 20, 23–48 (2006).32 A. Barnea, H. Cronqvist, S. Siegel, Nature or nurture: What determines investor behavior?. J. Financ. Econ. 98, 583–604 (2010).33 M. O. Jackson, Networks and economic behavior. Annu. Rev. Econ. 1, 489–511 (2009).34 P. J. Richerson, R. Boyd, A dual inheritance model of the human evolutionary process I: Basic postulates and a simple model. J. Soc. Biol. Struct. 1, 127– 154 (1978).35 A. Bisin, T. Verdier, The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences. J. Econ. Theor. 97, 298–319 (2001).36 T. Lux, Time variation of second moments from a noise trader/infection model. J. Econ. Dynam. Contr. 22, 1–38 (1997).37 S. Alfarano, T. Lux, A noise trader model as a generator of apparent financial power laws and long memory. Macroecon. Dyn. 11, 80– 101 (2007).38 W. A. Brock, C. H. Hommes,“Models of complexity in economics and finance”in System Dynamics in Economic and Financial Models, C. Heij, H. Schumacher,B. Hanzon, K. Praagman, Eds. (Wiley, Hoboken, NJ, 1997), pp. 3–41.39 C. Chiarella, R. Dieci, X. Z. He, K. Li, An evolutionary CAPM under heterogeneous beliefs. Ann. Finance 9, 185–215 (2013).40 R. Z. Heimer, D. Simon, Facebook finance: How social interaction propagates active investing. Working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland (2015). https:// www.clevelandfed.org/en/newsroom-and-events/publications/working-papers/2015-working-papers/wp-1522-facebook-finance-social-interaction-investing. aspx. Accessed 8 February 2021.41 L. M. Escobar Pradilla, A. Pedraza, Active trading and (poor) performance. Working paper, World Bank (2019). https://ssrn.com/abstract=3348770 Accessed 8 February 2021.42 J. N. Lane, S. S. Lim, B. Uzzi, Biased information transmission in investor social networks: Evidence from professional traders. Working paper, Harvard University(2020). https://www.aeaweb.org/conference/2021/preliminary/paper/NEaz28nz. Accessed 8 February 2021.43 B. Han, D. Hirshleifer, J. Walden, Social transmission bias and investor behavior. J. Financ. Quant. Anal., 10.1017/S0022109021000077 (2021).44 J. Chevalier, G. Ellison, Risk taking by mutual funds as a response to incentives. J. Polit. Econ. 105, 1167– 1200 (1997).45 M. Kaustia, S. Knüpfer, Peer performance and stock market entry. J. Financ. Econ. 104, 321–338 (2012).46 J. Gillespie, Polymorphism in random environments. Theor. Popul. Biol. 4, 193– 195 (1973).47 T. J. Brennan, A. W. Lo, The origin of behavior. Q. J. Finance. 1, 55– 108 (2011).48 D. Laibson, Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Q. J. Econ. 112, 443–477 (1997).49 F. D’Acunto, A. G. Rossi, M. Weber, Crowdsourcing peer information to change spending behavior. Working paper, Boston College (2020). https://ssrn.com/ abstract=3339335. Accessed 8 February 2021.50 D. A. Hirshleifer, J. Plotkin, Moonshots, investment booms, and selection bias in the transmission of cultural traits. Working paper, University of California, Irvine(2020). https://ssrn.com/abstract=3683611. Accessed 8 February 2021.51 D. Duffie, G. Manso, Information percolation in large markets. Am. Econ. Rev. 97, 203–209 (2007).52 H. N. Özsöylev, J. Walden, Asset pricing in large information networks. J. Econ. Theor. 146, 2252–2280 (2011).53 J. A. Bohren, Informational herding with model misspecification. J. Econ. Theor. 163, 222–247 (2016).54 A. Banerjee, A simple model of herd behavior. Q. J. Econ. 107, 797–817 (1992).55 S. Bikhchandani, D. Hirshleifer, I. Welch, A theory of fads, fashion, custom, and cultural change as informational cascades. J. Polit. Econ. 100, 992– 1026 (1992).56 C. Chamley, D. Gale, Information revelation and strategic delay in irreversible decisions. Econometrica 62, 1065– 1085 (1994).57 I. H. Lee, Market crashes and informational avalanches. Rev. Econ. Stud. 65, 741–759 (1998).58 J. Walden, Trading, profits, and volatility in a dynamic information network model. Rev. Econ. Stud. 86, 2248–2283 (2019).59 D. Andrei, J. Cujean, Information percolation, momentum and reversal. J. Financ. Econ. 123, 617–645 (2017).60 N. Jegadeesh, Evidence of predictable behavior of security returns. J. Finance 45, 881–898 (1990).61 W. F. M. DeBondt, R. H. Thaler, Does the stock market overreact? J. Finance 40, 793–808 (1985).62 N. Jegadeesh, S. Titman, Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for stock market efficiency. J. Finance 48, 65–91 (1993).63 E. L. Glaeser, J. A. Scheinkman,“Nonmarket interactions”in Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Eighth World Congress,M. Dewatripont, L. P. Hansen, S. J. Turnovsky, Eds. (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, 2003), vol. 1, pp. 339–365.64 D. Hirshleifer, S. H. Teoh,“Thought and behavior contagion in capital markets”in Handbook of Financial Markets: Dynamics and Evolution, Handbooks in Finance, T. Hens, K. Schenk-Hoppe, Eds. (North-Holland, Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2009), pp. 1–46.65 M. Kelly, C. O. O’Grada, Market contagion: Evidence from the panics of 1854 and 1857. Am. Econ. Rev. 90, 1110– 1124 (2000).66 E. Duflo, E. Saez, Participation and investment decisions in a retirement plan: The influence of colleagues’choices. J. Publ. Econ. 85, 121– 148 (2002).67 H. G. Hong, J. D. Kubik, J. C. Stein, Social interaction and stock market participation. J. Finance 59, 137– 163 (2004).68 J. R. Brown, Z. Ivkovic´, P. A. Smith, S. Weisbenner, Neighbors matter: Causal community effects and stock market participation. J. Finance 63, 1509– 1531 (2008).69 S. Shive, An epidemic model of investor behavior. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 45, 169– 198 (2010).70 M. Massa, A. Simonov, Is college a focal point of investor life? Rev. Finance 15, 757–797 (2011).71 R. Heimer, Peer pressure: Social interaction and the disposition effect. Rev. Financ. Stud. 29, 3177–3209 (2016).72 W. O. Kermack, A. G. McKendrick, A contribution to the mathematical theory of epidemics. Proc. Math. Phys. Eng. Sci. 115, 700–721 (1927).73 C. Burnside, M. Eichenbaum, S. T. Rebelo, Understanding booms and busts in housing markets. J. Polit. Econ. 124, 1088– 1147 (2016).74 A. Chinco, The madness of crowds and the likelihood of bubbles. Working paper, University of Chicago (2020). https://ssrn.com/abstract=3518021. Accessed 8 February 2021.75 R. J. Shiller, Irrational Exuberance (Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, 2000).76 M. Bailey, R. Cao, T. Kuchler, J. Stroebel, A. Wong, Social connectedness: Measurement, determinants, and effects. J. Econ. Perspect. 32, 259–280 (2018).77 R. Z. Heimer, Friends do let friends buy stocks actively. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 107, 527–540 (2014).78 D. Georgarakos, G. Pasini, Trust, sociability, and stock market participation. Rev. Finance 15, 693–725 (2011).79 A. Kumar, Who gambles in the stock market? J. Finance 64, 1889– 1933 (2009).80 R. Romano, For diversity in the international regulation of financial institutions: Critiquing and recalibrating the Basel architecture. Yale J. Regul. 31, 1–76 (2014).81 R. Romano, S. Levin, Sunsetting as an adaptive strategy. Working paper, Yale University (2020). https://ssrn.com/abstract=3655900. Accessed 8 February 2021.82 J. A. Berger, C. Heath, Idea habitats: How the prevalence of environmental cues influences the success of ideas. Cognit. Sci. 29, 195–221 (2005).83 K. D. Daniel, T. J. Moskowitz, Momentum crashes. J. Financ. Econ. 122, 221–247 (2016).84 E. F. Fama, K. R. French, The cross-section of expected stock returns. J. Finance 47, 427–465 (1992).